Rechercher dans ce blog

Wednesday, June 30, 2021

Former CEA Kaushik Basu decodes borderlands where politics and economics meet in new book - Economic Times

I am now convinced that economic policy is so poorly crafted because it is developed by consensus among politicians. If an airplane was designed by this method — the wing should have an upward tilt because that is what seemed right to a majority, the nose should tilt left because that is what the majority wants —it would, in all likelihood, not fly.

Indian democracy has the disadvantage of a vertical structure. Everybody gets involved in every decision. You can see this from those ubiquitous government folders which travel from desk to desk, gathering no-objection signatures, before anything is approved. It is often felt this is what democracy is all about. Everybody or a majority has to be in approval for a decision to move. This is best described as a ‘vertical democracy’.

But there can be another kind of democracy. Everybody has a say but not on all decisions. All the decisions are partitioned so that you get to have a voice for only the ones in your domain. India needs to shift from its relatively vertical structure of permission system which slows down decisions to a more horizontal, partitioned democracy.


When it comes to economic decision-making, it is a pity that it is not recognised that economics has a technical, engineering-type side to it. While economics is indeed open-ended and nebulous in some ways, in some areas, it can be used with as much sharpness as in engineering projects.

Auctions are a good example. Government can do vastly better if it sells resources not by evaluating them by themselves, setting price and selling it off, but by selling it off through well-designed auctions, which would endogenously determine what the price is. (GoI would eventually do this, for 3G spectrum auctions, with huge success in fund-raising, but also drawing attention to the fact that it raised much less than it could have in earlier 2G auctions.)

Another thing that I have learned is that in the Indian bureaucracy — and maybe this is a feature of bureaucracies everywhere — to any question that you may be asked, you never say you don’t have an answer. If you don’t have an answer to the question asked, then give an answer to a question for which you do have an answer, never mind no one asked that question.

It’s Really Engineering
It is fascinating watching the government from within. I earlier took Keynes’ remark on the greater importance of ideas than vested interests in the shaping of the world as nice but a bit self-serving for an academic. I spouted it often as a professor because it raised my status, but I didn’t really believe it. Now, having taken leave from academe and come into the world of policy, for the first time I believe that Keynes had hit upon a fundamental truth. It is the lack of imagination and the grip of stale ideas on political leaders and career bureaucrats that have a tendency to stall good policy. I also now feel convinced that economics as a discipline is not just a stunning intellectual achievement but it is, in practice, a very useful discipline.

Admittedly, economics has many areas where policy has to rely on little science and a lot of judgement and common sense. But there are also fields, such as the design of auctions, the fine print of antitrust laws and the methods of giving food or other subsidies, which are beginning to resemble engineering. Ideas from these fields can be put to great use. One has to see them not being used to realise their value.

India’s food procurement policy is riddled with such obvious fallacies. I have been in numerous meetings on food price inflation where bureaucrats insist that the Indian government must at all times hold on to some minimal food reserve because food is such a vital need. What they miss out on is that if a certain amount of reserve is held at all times, as a rule, they may as well not hold that reserve.

But it is very difficult to make seasoned minds see this. There are many other ideas that can bring some quick relief but it is a battle to make people change tradition. I regret that I am not pushy enough to get my ideas into practice. I feel some of them are so obviously good that any clever person would want to use them once they hear about them. As it happens, only the prime minister [Manmohan Singh] seems to see clearly some of these ideas that I bring up in meetings.

The more I see the prime minister alongside other politicians, the more I am convinced he stands head and shoulders above them. Like Nehru, he is truly passionate about India. My conversations with him are almost never about politics and everyday political machination. It is always about what we can do to enable India to do better. I am aware that this may not be of much value since political intrigue is such an important ingredient of political life. Only if voters were a little more sophisticated to understand this, we would have a more successful nation.

Of Sweet Nothings
I am amazed at how much we human beings can talk when we have little to say. The ploy is to take cover behind nice-sounding statements. Take economic recovery. Some economists agree we are about to see a V-shaped recovery. Others say it will be U-shaped, whereby we will stay at the bottom for a while. Then there are the proponents of a W-shaped recovery, which involves a second dip. Some agree it will be a J-shaped recovery where we will ultimately rise beyond where we were, unless of course we have an L-shaped recovery in which we have to be reconciled to there being no recovery. Think of literally any letter of the English alphabet and there is some economist who believes we are about to see that letter-shaped recovery.

What all this shows is that we have little idea about the nature of recovery but will not admit to that. A lot of these monetary policy discussions occur nowadays by slipping into health analogies which sound nice, but mean little. When a person who has bad health refuses to exercise, we don’t allow the person to sit on the couch and die, we try to coax the person on to the treadmill. So we hear experts saying, ‘We must get Greece on the treadmill; otherwise its economy will die.’ The audience nods sagely. But what does ‘getting Greece on the treadmill’ mean? Moreover, it is not at all clear what the death of a nation means.

If I am right that much of what these monetary policy experts say has little content, how do they understand one another? After all, they do agree, disagree, discuss and debate. My hypothesis is that this is like the twitter of birds. Birds do not understand one another (admittedly, that is our presumption) but still they have seeming conversations.

To test this out, in the middle of the Toronto discussion on monetary policy in G20 countries, I decided to offer a meaningless comment which used the right words and had the right sound bites. But the comment had no meaning — at least no meaning to the person making the comment. It was fascinating to see my audience agree and disagree with me. Judging by the animated discussion that this gave rise to, the group clearly found it meaningful and deep. I write this in a light vein but I am serious about this aspect of some parts of economics.

I do not for a moment think this is true of all economics. There is a huge amount of meaning to what Ken Arrow wrote, John Hicks wrote, Paul Samuelson wrote. There is Euclidean elegance and meaning in what Gérard Debreu did. There are some stunning, almost magical, insights in some of the theoretical works of Joe Stiglitz and George Akerlof. But many policy experts, especially in the area of macroeconomic policymaking, take advantage of the core of economics which is deep, and talk, whereof one should be silent, to sort of quote Wittgenstein.

But there is one puzzle. If my hypothesis is right, how come central banks do their job reasonably well, as they seem to? I believe the answer has to do with evolutionary behaviour. Central banks use rules of thumb regarding repo rates and various policy rates.

The reasons they give for their choice of particular rules are not compelling, but the rules of thumb they follow (and the actions that these rules lead to) work because the bad rules of thumb, which led to adverse reaction, have over the years been dismissed.

So the policy rules actually used are not the ones we can demonstrate will work, but they nevertheless serve some purpose by the laws of evolution. The bad rules have, in effect, gone extinct. You do not need any special understanding to get to this just as the giraffe does not have to understand the value of a long neck in order to have one.

Two problems make the Indian government less efficient and less effective: overwork in the top echelons of bureaucracy, and the culture of permissionism that pervades the government. At one level, it is impressive that virtually all civil servants who are fairly senior, or are striving to be so, work extremely hard.

A slightly less charitable view of this phenomenon is that the senior bureaucrats often work as back-end, on-call workers for their master — the minister or some member of Parliament. And like the on-call workers in the feudal landlord’s manor, once they are part of this system, they have no choice but to plod away 14 hours a day, seven days a week. Whatever be the cause — ambition, diligence, drive or exploitation — the upshot is that they work to the point where efficiency and creativity suffer.

These individuals, though initially very bright, come to acquire a parrotlike quality, with the ability to do a large amount of mechanical work. This does hamper creativity in the government.

The other problem is what can only be called the malaise of permissionism. For a newcomer arriving straight into the top echelon of government, as was the case with me, what is immediately noticeable is how everyone is always taking permission. The requests for permission generally get passed up the pyramidal structure of the government; and a surprising amount of trivia go all the way to the top, namely, to the minister.

You want to go to Varanasi for a day to attend to an ailing relative, you want to change the brand of coffee served in the ministry, you feel there should be another attendant to keep the bathrooms clean. All such proposals move in a chain of hard cardboard folders, tied with strings, from one room to another, acquiring notings from senior members of the bureaucracy.

This is such a far cry from the American university where senior professors are allocated budgets and can with a stroke of a pen get a visitor to come from New Delhi, Tokyo or Istanbul, all paid for. The system there is not one of prior permission but periodic review to make sure that no one is misusing authority.

I know that the switch over to such a system will initially cause some corruption and misuse. But the alternative is so inefficient that we have to try change the system. Moreover, being given some final authority on matters nurtures trust and a sense of responsibility and even honesty. There will be some initial misuse but that has to be treated as transition cost. We have to remember that even with all these cumbersome checks and balances, we are not known for the absence of corruption.

The Inflation Superstition Wherever I go, I find a raging debate and discussion on India’s inflation. There is palpable anger that this is all deliberately caused by the government. This is completely wrong. Once inflation gets started (and there is no doubt that government has some responsibility for that), it is difficult to control. It has to be a slow process bringing inflation down because otherwise you can crash the economy.

Of all the economic ills, inflation is one that governments do not want because people do not need official data to realise this is happening.

Each person knows this almost every morning or evening when they buy the day’s supply of food or go shopping. Inflation causes the popularity of governments to fall more than any other economic ill, from growth slowdown and recession, to rising unemployment. I have now understood why people assume inflation is deliberately caused by the government.

Human beings have a propensity to believe that someone or some well-defined agency is wilfully responsible for whatever happens. It is this propensity that has led humans to many false beliefs through the ages, ranging from god having created the universe to governments causing inflation to persist.

Rights & Wrongs of Rights
…I write a letter to the prime minister (he has asked for this) about the new Food Security Bill and what its weaknesses were. I believe a right to food law is a good idea but its current design needs lots of correction.

Well-meaning activists push for too many needs to be enshrined as rights — the Right to X, Y and Z, unmindful of the critical principle, commonly attributed to Immanuel Kant: ‘ought implies can’. When you say someone has a right to something (or someone ought to get something), it must be the case that there is some way to fulfil that right.

An ought or a right that is not feasible is a meaningless normative injunction. It is for this reason that I have opposed giving everyone the right to work that some activists have pushed for. I have clashed with activists on this, on the simple ground that I do not think in a large and complex economy such as India, this right is feasible.

There is no way we can guarantee everyone gets a job. To write down every basic need as a right recognised by the government is a travesty of the ‘ought implies can’ principle. It is actually worse. By declaring too many such rights which by definition will not be satisfied, we debase the nation’s law and the meaning of rights itself. Then when we declare a right that can be guaranteed, no one pays heed to it. The law languishes on paper, as happens for so many laws in India. The right to food, I think, is feasible.

Government can guarantee this because it can take steps to ensure it is fulfilled. But even with such rights, we have to keep in mind that there may arise times when there is an aggregate shortfall in food. In those times, everyone cannot be guaranteed a basic minimum food. We should spell out explicitly how we would handle those special occasions, when the ‘can’ of the Kantian injunction may not be fulfilled.

Adblock test (Why?)


Former CEA Kaushik Basu decodes borderlands where politics and economics meet in new book - Economic Times
Read More

Construction Economics for July 5, 2021 | 2021-06-30 - Engineering News-Record

Construction Economics for July 5, 2021 | 2021-06-30 | Engineering News-Record

Adblock test (Why?)


Construction Economics for July 5, 2021 | 2021-06-30 - Engineering News-Record
Read More

Ball State University Community Mourns the loss of Dr Steven Horwitz - Ball State University News

With great sadness, the Miller College of Business at Ball State University announces the death of Steven G. Horwitz, Distinguished Professor of Free Enterprise in the Department of Economics and Director of the Institute for the Study of Political Economy (ISPE). Dr. Horwitz died Sunday, June 27, after a nearly four-year, courageous battle with multiple myeloma.

"Steve was an extraordinary economics scholar and researcher, but he would tell you he was a teacher first," said Dr. Todd Nesbit, Assistant Professor of Free Enterprise and Entrepreneurial Economics at Ball State. "He loved teaching and was eagerly anticipating the return of students to campus this Fall. Steve inspired us with his positivity about how exploring ideas can bring about prosperity for all. He was particularly interested in seeking how best to empower those who have been historically marginalized."

Dr. Horwitz was memorialized on social media by colleagues and friends around the globe—many of whom had never met him in person but regarded him as a teacher, mentor, and friend.

On Forbes.com, Art Carden remembered Dr. Horwitz as "a dedicated scholar, a passionate teacher, a good friend, and an insightful mentor." Trevor Burrus, a research fellow in the Cato Institute, called him "the great libertarian economist and my friend … a teacher, a father, a husband, a communicator, a mentor, a Rush fan, a scholar, a writer, a pontificator, and much more."

Dr. Horwitz was Distinguished Professor of Free Enterprise in the Department of Economics at Ball State. He also was the Director of the Institute for the Study of Political Economy in the Miller College of Business. He had a PhD in Economics from George Mason University and an AB in Economics and Philosophy from The University of Michigan.

Dr. Horwitz was the author of four books: Monetary Evolution, Free Banking, and Economic Order (Westview, 1992); Microfoundations and Macroeconomics: An Austrian Perspective (Routledge, 2000); Hayek's Modern Family: Classical Liberalism and the Evolution of Social Institutions (Palgrave Macmillan, 2015); and Austrian Economics: An Introduction (Cato Institute, 2020). He has written extensively on Austrian economics, Hayek's political economy, monetary theory and history, and American economic history.

Dr. Horwitz's work has been published in professional journals such as History of Political Economy, Southern Economic Journal, and The Cambridge Journal of Economics.

Dr. Horwitz was an Affiliated Senior Scholar at the Mercatus Center in Arlington, Va., a Senior Fellow at the Fraser Institute in Canada, and Economics Editor at the Cato Institute's libertarianism.org project. A guest on numerous radio and cable TV shows, he was the 2020 recipient of the Julian L. Simon Memorial Award from the Competitive Enterprise Institute and a member of the Mont Pelerin Society.

Dr. Horwitz was a guest speaker to professional, student, policymaker, and general audiences throughout North America, Europe, Asia, South America. He was also Dana Professor of Economics Emeritus at St. Lawrence University in Canton, NY, where he taught for 28 years.

"Steve was really proud of the work of the Institute for the Study of Political Economy," Dr. Nesbit said. "ISPE is proud to continue to expand our research and public events in Steve's honor."

Dr. Horwitz is survived by his beloved wife, Sarah Skwire; father, Ronald; children Andrew Horwitz, Rachel Horwitz, Abigail Waschow, and Penelope Waschow; and his faithful sheepadoodle, Panda. He is also survived by brothers Michael (Laura Marchak) Horwitz, David (Laurie) Horwitz, and Robert (Dr. Amy) Horwitz, and by many nieces, nephews, other family members and friends.

A private family service for Dr. Horwitz took place on June 30 in Farmington Hills, Mich. A public celebration of his life will be scheduled for later this summer in Indianapolis.

Adblock test (Why?)


Ball State University Community Mourns the loss of Dr Steven Horwitz - Ball State University News
Read More

Economist: $2.5B to abate opioid crisis in WVa community - ABC News

A forensic economist has testified that a 15-year plan to abate the opioid crisis in a West Virginia community will cost local officials $2.5 billion

HUNTINGTON, W.Va. -- A 15-year plan to abate the opioid crisis in a West Virginia community will cost local officials $2.5 billion, a forensic economist has testified.

George Barrett testified Tuesday that Cabell County and the city of Huntington would need to spend $144 million to implement the plan and the annual cost would rise to $197 million by the 15th year, The Herald-Dispatch reported. The governments have combined annual budgets of less than $87 million.

The testimony came in the seventh week of a landmark civil trial against three large opioid distributors. A lawsuit filed by Cabell County and the city of Huntington accuses drug distributors AmerisourceBergen Drug Co., Cardinal Health Inc. and McKesson Corp. of fueling the U.S. crisis. The plaintiffs argue that the companies created a “public nuisance” by flooding the area with tens of millions of opioid doses over eight years and ignoring the signs that the small community along the Ohio River was being ravaged by addiction.

The companies, in turn, say poor communication and pill quotas set by federal agents are to blame, along with a rise in prescriptions written by doctors.

Testimony this week has focused on the drug abatement plan and its cost.

Barrett's findings were based on the report of Caleb Alexander, a pharmacoepidemiologist at the Johns Hopkins University School of Medicine. Alexander came up with an abatement plan for the community he said could reduce overdoses, overdose deaths and the number of people with opioid use disorder by half.

McKesson attorney Timothy Hester questioned Barrett's qualifications in coming up with the estimate, which he called inflated.

The Cabell-Huntington Health Department spent about $225,000 on its harm reduction program in 2019, but the abatement plan calls for expanding the program.

Hester also said the majority of medical claims are paid through Medicaid, not city and county officials. He asked that the judge to toss the testimony, but the judge did not immediately rule.

Adblock test (Why?)


Economist: $2.5B to abate opioid crisis in WVa community - ABC News
Read More

Fed's Waller Says Economic Progress Warrants Earlier Taper - Bloomberg

Sign up for the New Economy Daily newsletter, follow us @economics and subscribe to our podcast.

Federal Reserve Governor Christopher Waller said the better-than-expected performance of the U.S. economy warrants scaling back asset purchases sooner than expected and he favors starting with mortgage backed securities.

“We are now in a different phase of economic policy so it is appropriate to start thinking about pulling back on some of the stimulus,” Waller said in a Bloomberg TV interview on Tuesday. “I am much more sympathetic to tapering MBS first.”

The Fed held interest rates near zero at its June 15-16 meeting and signaled it would probably keep them there until 2023 to help the U.S. economy recover from Covid-19. Officials also pledged to keep buying $120 billion of Treasuries and mortgage-backed securities a month until “substantial further progress” had been made on employment and inflation goals.

Taper Timing

“This year has been a surprise. None of us back in December would have thought the economy would be where it is right now,” Waller said. “Given the way the economy has progressed, I think everybody anticipates tapering could move up earlier than when they originally thought. Whether that’s this year, we’ll see, but it certainly could.”

A number of Fed officials, including St. Louis Fed’s James Bullard and Kansas City President Esther George, have suggested that the tapering of bond buying be more weighted toward mortgage-backed securities because surging home prices suggest the market doesn’t need additional central bank support.

“Right now the housing market is on fire. They don’t need any other unnecessary support so I would be all in favor of that,” Waller said.

The Fed's New Dot Plot

Economic projections released at their meeting showed 13 of 18 officials favored at least one rate increase by the end of 2023, versus seven in March. Eleven officials saw at least two hikes by the end of that year. In addition, seven of them saw a move as early as 2022, up from four.

Waller said he was not one of those who had pulled his dot projection forward. He declined to say in which year he favored liftoff, but did suggest that scaling back bond buying should come first.

“I myself would like to see tapering over before we consider raising rates,” Waller said. “Therefore if you think you may have to raise rates in late 2022 or early 2023, you pretty much want to get tapering done by the end of next year if possible.”

The former research director of the St. Louis Fed, Waller was sworn onto the Board in Washington in December after the U.S. Senate confirmed his nomination by former President Donald Trump.

(Updates with more Waller comments from fourth paragraph.)

    Adblock test (Why?)


    Fed's Waller Says Economic Progress Warrants Earlier Taper - Bloomberg
    Read More

    Economists predict multiple US interest rate rises by end of 2023 - Financial Times

    Elevated inflation will compel the Federal Reserve to raise US interest rates at least twice by the end of 2023, according to a new poll of leading academic economists for the Financial Times.

    The inaugural survey conducted by the FT and the Initiative on Global Markets at the University of Chicago’s Booth School of Business points to a potentially more hawkish path for monetary policy than indicated by the Fed’s chair, Jay Powell.

    The economists’ views align closely with the “dot plot” of Fed officials’ own forecasts for when and how quickly rates will have to rise from their current level near zero, as the US economy rebounds from the pandemic and inflation runs ahead of the long-term average targeted by the Fed.

    Publication of the latest dot plot sent a jolt through markets earlier this month, as policymakers moved up their timing for expected lift-off, but Powell and other members of the Fed leadership intervened later to insist they would be patient in keeping monetary policy highly accommodative.

    The FT-IGM US Macroeconomists Survey polled 52 academic economists on the likelihood that the Fed’s main policy rate would indeed be higher by 0.50 percentage points by the end of 2023, as the dot plot indicated. A majority said the likelihood of a move of that size or greater was above 75 per cent, and a large minority put it as high as 90 per cent.

    Three economists said it was a certainty.

    Strip plot showing economist's projections for rate hikes by the end of 2023

    The survey underscores the challenge facing the central bank to convey a clear message about its evolving monetary policy stance. Powell warned that dot plot forecasts of future rate increases should be taken with “a grain of salt”, but other officials have begun to float earlier timelines for the first rate increases.

    “As inflation goes up and the economy improves, the traditional hawk-dove differences across the Federal Open Market Committee are going to start to reappear,” said Alan Blinder of Princeton University, who was a vice-chair of the Fed in the 1990s and participated in the survey. “You are seeing it now, and you are going to see more of it.”

    Blinder said he forecast an interest rate increase as early as 2022.

    FT-IGM survey respondents see inflation as the biggest driver of Fed officials’ changing thinking on the timing of rate rises, citing it as the main factor more frequently than the improving outlook for the US jobs market or rising house prices.

    Consumer prices have surged this year beyond even some of the loftiest estimates. Core PCE, the inflation measure targeted by the Fed, was running at an annual rate of 3.4 per cent in May, its highest in 29 years, as strong demand for goods and services in the improving economy collided with widespread supply chain constraints.

    The FT-IGM survey, which ran between June 25 and June 28 and will be conducted regularly throughout the year, shows that economists are highly attuned to the risk of elevated inflation. Survey respondents’ median forecast for core PCE at the end of this year was 3 per cent — the same prediction as the median Fed official.

    But two-thirds of the respondents said it was “somewhat” or “very” likely this metric would still exceed 2 per cent on a year-over-year basis by the end of 2022. The median forecast of Fed officials is for 2.1 per cent at the end of next year.

    “It is hard to think of a more pro-inflation environment,” said Nicholas Bloom, an economist at Stanford University, who participated in the survey. “The Fed has been as aggressive as it can be in promoting growth, fiscal policy is incredibly relaxed and there are supply constraints.”

    Despite the “perfect storm” that Bloom said has formed to push consumer prices higher, he dismissed concerns that inflationary pressures would get out of hand in the long-run, not least because the Fed is on hand to act.

    Three-quarters of the FT-IGM survey respondents said it was unlikely market expectations for long-term inflation would rise significantly to over 3 per cent by the start of next year. Expectations are currently for long-term inflation of 2.3 per cent.

    “An essential part of the Fed maintaining their credibility is being responsive to the incoming data,” said another respondent, Karen Dynan of Harvard University.

    Bar chart showing economists' responses to the question "What is your estimate of the likelihood that five-year five-year forward inflation compensation will exceed 3 percent at the end of the first week of January 2022?" in the FT-IGM survey of more than 50 economists (Five-year five-year forwards indicate what five-year inflation expectations will be in five years’ time, derived from the expected difference between yields on Treasuries and inflation-protected government bonds.) Three-quarters of respondents say it is 'very unlikely' or 'somewhat unlikely' that inflation expectations will exceed 3% in 2022.

    The central bank has already begun discussing when it will begin scaling back its $120bn monthly asset purchase programme, which officials have pledged to maintain until they achieve “substantial further progress” on their goals of 2 per cent average inflation and full employment.

    The FT-IGM survey showed substantial disagreement about the outlook for economic growth in 2021, even with almost half the year in the rear-view mirror.

    The median forecast was for a gross domestic product rebound of 6.5 per cent, after the economy contracted 3.5 per cent last year. But the economists were also asked to set out a plausible range of outcomes, and these more often skewed to the downside than the upside.

    The high degree of variation suggests “there is considerable uncertainty about how fast service sectors will bounce back, whether labour market shortages will hamper growth and how savings [and] consumption will respond once fiscal stimulus is dialled down”, said Allan Timmermann, a professor at University of California at San Diego, who helped design the survey.

    Box plot showing economists' forecasts for US GDP growth in 2021, according to the FT-IGM survey of more than 50 economists. The median forecast is 6.5%, however there is substantial variation in the predictions. 18 economists believe the tail risk skews to the downside, while 7 (who are relatively gloomy in their forecasts) see more upside potential. The rest believe the risks are evenly distributed.


    Adblock test (Why?)


    Economists predict multiple US interest rate rises by end of 2023 - Financial Times
    Read More

    Tuesday, June 29, 2021

    China has gone 'too far' in clamping down on big tech — that will hurt economic growth, says analyst - CNBC

    The Chinese government has gone "too far" in cracking down on large technology companies — that will hurt innovation and slow down economic growth, an analyst said Tuesday.

    Regulators in China have in the last few months ramped up scrutiny on the country's tech giants such as Alibaba and Tencent. The companies now face fines and new rules aimed at reining in monopolistic business practices.

    "There's certainly a logic to clamping down on monopolies and some of the abuses of power that we see from some of the companies. But they've gone too far and basically scared innovators from innovating," said Scott Kennedy, senior advisor and trustee chair in Chinese business and economics at the Center for Strategic and International Studies.

    Kennedy explained to CNBC's "Street Signs Asia" that the private sector is an important source of productivity gains that fuel much of China's economic growth.

    There's certainly a logic to clamping down ... But they've gone too far and basically scared innovators from innovating.
    Scott Kennedy
    Center for Strategic and International Studies

    But the regulatory crackdown may hinder the formation of new companies, while existing firms — particularly small ones — may be scared to make investments in the future, he added.

    "That's where all of China's important, good, high productivity growth lays, and which we may never see as a result of the clampdown that we're seeing right now," said Kennedy.

    That potential hit to China's growth prospects adds to the economic challenges confronting the ruling Chinese Communist Party, which this week marks its 100th year since its founding. China — the world's second-largest economy — is also grappling a mounting debt pile, an aging population and widening inequality.

    China's economic growth outlook

    The World Bank on Tuesday raised its 2021 economic forecast for China, citing an "effective suppression" of Covid-19 as helping the country's recovery. The bank expects the Chinese economy to grow 8.5% this year, higher than its previous forecast of 8.1% expansion.

    Last year, China's economy grew 2.3% from a year ago — making it the only major economy that recorded growth as the coronavirus spread globally.

    Kennedy said China will likely "primarily depend" on state-led investments to boost growth in the next decade. That's because consumption, while growing, has not bounced back from the pandemic to levels seen in investments, he added.

    To boost consumption, China needs to liberalize parts of its services sector so that consumers have additional ways to spend their money, said Kennedy.

    "We all have seen this coming, but ... it's still a bridge too far in the short term at least," said the analyst.

    Chinese authorities want to reduce the economy's reliance on debt-fueled investments for growth. But their multi-year effort to deleverage took a pause last year due to the pandemic, sending China's debt-to-GDP ratio to an all-time high of nearly 290% in the third quarter, data by the Bank of International Settlements showed.

    — CNBC's Evelyn Cheng contributed to this report.

    Adblock test (Why?)


    China has gone 'too far' in clamping down on big tech — that will hurt economic growth, says analyst - CNBC
    Read More

    'Fat' 401(k)s causing people to retire early: Oxford Economics - Yahoo Finance

    The stock market’s all-time highs are doing wonders for workers’ 401(k)s, with the largest number of 401(k) and IRA millionaires in history, according to Fidelity data.

    As a result, many people are dropping out of the workforce to retire earlier than planned, turning their backs on a job seeker’s market.

    The Federal Reserve is letting the economy run especially hot in an attempt to bring back people into the workforce, Oxford Economics' senior economist Bob Schwartz wrote in a note to clients. But that hot economy and resulting hot market mean bigger 401(k) balances – so some workers may not feel as compelled to continue working when they check their inflated retirement accounts.

    “Some of the retirees may come back if the job market is hot enough, but the muscular boost to 401(k) plans over the past year may keep a larger fraction of senior workers on the golf course than anticipated,” Schwartz wrote.

    Last year, account balances increased 21% on average, largely thanks to the market’s rise, rather than contributions, Vanguard reported. The fund firm’s average and median 401(k) balances in 2020 hit $129,157 and $33,472, respectively.

    Schwartz pointed out that the number of people who have retired has spiked since the pandemic began, with 2.5 million workers deciding enough is enough. Amid early pandemic layoffs, a lot of that was probably involuntary, as people cared for family members, lost their jobs. According to a May Federal Reserve report, 29% of 2020’s retirees retired due to the pandemic.

    The Fed wrote that it’s likely many who retired because of Covid-19 would return to work, and now given the improved job market, there’s even more reason to go back to work.

    The big question, then, is whether these two factors balance each other out. Oxford Economics says no.

    “One likely reason is that ageing baby boomers are entering their golden years with considerably stronger balance sheets than they expected, thanks to surging asset prices and lower debt burdens,” Schwartz wrote, noting that household wealth increased 23% ($25.6 trillion) over the past year thanks to rising home values and ever-higher stock market.

    “However, wealthy households with the fattest portfolios reaped the biggest gains, and it’s unlikely that their appreciated assets greatly affected retirement decisions,” Schwartz continued. “That said, it’s important to remember that older households hold more wealth than younger ones, and the improved balance sheets of senior workers may well have tipped them over into retirement.”

    This would include even those in lower-paying jobs, which often provide access to retirement plans.

    “Here the improvement over the past year has been even more remarkable. According to the Federal Reserve data, assets in defined contribution plans, mostly 401(k)s, surged by 34% over the past year, exceeding the gain in the broader measure of net worth by the widest margin in at least a decade,” Schwartz wrote.

    With that big gain, according to Schwartz, “it’s not a stretch to believe that some senior workers feel they have enough to retire on a few years before their planned exit from the labor force.”

    “Historically, when people retire,” he continued, “there is only a slim chance they return to work.”

    Ethan Wolff-Mann is a writer at Yahoo Finance focusing on consumer issues, personal finance, retail, airlines, and more. Follow him on Twitter @ewolffmann.

    Read more:

    Follow Yahoo Finance on Twitter, Facebook, Instagram, Flipboard, LinkedIn, YouTube, and reddit

    Adblock test (Why?)


    'Fat' 401(k)s causing people to retire early: Oxford Economics - Yahoo Finance
    Read More

    Economics and US National Security - War on the Rocks

    The Biden administration has explicitly linked its foreign policy agenda to the goal of improving the economic circumstances of the United States, especially the middle class. It seems natural that a country would connect its prosperity to how it navigates the often-treacherous waters of international relations. But are these goals — national wealth and security — easily pursued together?

    There are at least five big issues to consider when assessing the goal of linking America’s economic well-being to its national security policies. First, while there are similarities and connections, a state’s national security goals often pull in different directions than its foreign economic ambitions, which themselves can be at odds with its domestic economic priorities. Where are the tensions between economics and national security, and can a thoughtful grand strategy overcome them? Second, it is important to comprehend how the American economy functions — both in the past and the present — and to better understand what role federal policy has played in its development. Third, what goals and values have animated U.S. economic statecraft in the past? The United States has, throughout its history, viewed the dangers and opportunities of the international economy differently than other states. Fourth, after pursuing a largely hands-off approach to the global economic order from its founding through the 1930s, the United States reversed course after World War II to pursue an ambitious foreign economic policy. This economic statecraft was consequential if at times inconsistent and erratic. Finally, the United States and the world are entering a new period of economic transformation that will generate difficult dilemmas and questions. How these dilemmas and questions are confronted will shape how successful the administration is in incorporating economics into its national security strategy, as well as shape the next decades for both the United States and the world.

    Tension Between Economics and Security

    Writ large, any national grand strategy should seek both prosperity and security, and there are many reasons to believe these goals are interconnected. Historically, however, there are at least four major tensions between foreign economic and national security policy.

    First is a chicken and egg story — which comes first, wealth or security? It is difficult to generate productive economic activity in an unstable, insecure environment. A national security policy that removes threats and dangers and provides stability creates a far better environment for economic growth. On the other hand, providing security is costly. Subsidizing standing militaries and bureaucracies that support them is not only expensive, but it also involves opportunity costs by removing otherwise productive citizens and organizations from contributing to the economy. Spending too much wealth on security (i.e., the military) can decrease a nation’s productivity and lead to economic decline. Privileging the economy over security, on the other hand, can lead to a state having less influence on the world order in which it operates. More worryingly, it can expose a state to coercion, predation, and even conquest. History provides stark examples of the danger of both spending too much and too little on security.

    The second dilemma is related and somewhat contradictory. While eliminating destabilizing violence and lawlessness is necessary for economic growth, the greatest periods of technological, governmental, financial, and even sociocultural innovation have often coincided with intense geopolitical competition and even war. Western Europe’s rise to economic dominance from the 17th through the middle of the 20th century can, in part, be attributed to a fierce security competition on the continent, where to fall behind was to risk second-rate status or even extinction. European imperialism was driven by similar pressures and propelled by the innovations produced by continental competition (modern banking and finance, efficient governance, steam, rail, telegraph, advanced medicine, etc.).  These in turn fostered similar reforms globally among nationalizing and decolonizing movements trying to escape the grip of European imperial power. It is no accident that the period that witnessed the greatest geopolitical upheaval also witnessed world historical economic growth and unprecedented increases in life expectancy. The foundations of the computing and telecommunications revolution, to give the most recent example of security-driven innovation, had its roots in the Cold War competition.

    Third, different theories and mechanisms drive the effort to acquire greater wealth as opposed to obtaining greater security. Success in economics is measured by absolute gain. Economic productivity and wealth creation is driven by the laws of comparative advantage, where exchange between individuals, communities, and nations is mutually beneficial. Security, on the other hand, is measured by relative power. In other words, it matters less how much a state’s power increases in absolute terms than how its position changes compared to its competitors. This generates a conundrum for grand strategy — should a state pursue global economic exchange that will increase its wealth if it also enriches, perhaps more, a potential adversary? This dilemma has been at the heart of U.S. policy toward China over the past 30 years.

    The fourth tension involves interdependence. Increased trade, commerce, and financial interactions between nations makes them more connected and in some sense dependent upon each other. Some argue this interdependence increases security, as nations develop a common interest in maintaining the mutual gain that comes from their shared, interwoven economic activity. Political scientists often refer to the capitalist peace. Others — who often self-identify as realists — worry this is an illusion. Ultimately, a state’s desire for security and power will always trump its desire for wealth and economic gain, and no level of interdependence will prevent it from pursuing its interests, even if those interests threaten a conflict that would undo the economic system and interdependence. Others even go so far as to suggest that interdependence dangerously increases a nation’s security vulnerability and may even heighten friction between states.

    Despite vigorous debate among international relations theorists, economists, and historians, there is no agreed upon resolution to these dilemmas between national security and economics. The best grand strategies are the ones that most effectively recognize and reconcile these tensions between security and economics. The United States has also long had a different way of viewing and resolving these tensions than other powers.

    America’s Economic History

    How should we understand the American economy — its history, current state, and future path? How is wealth generated and distributed, and how do these practices and outcomes compare to other states? Understanding how the U.S. economy works, and the role of national policy in its development, is critical to incorporating it into a national security strategy.

    The United States has long been a wealthy nation, even before its political founding. It became the world’s largest economy in the late 19th century, but not merely because of its size. It also had the largest per capita gross domestic product. Despite profound changes in the global economy, and the fact that the second-largest economy has changed often (Great Britain, Germany, the Soviet Union, Japan, now China), the United States has maintained its leading position for over 130 years. Its recent percentage of global GDP is not considerably different than it was in 1913.

    In the 19th and 20th centuries, the United States excelled at the activities that generated wealth in the modern world: agricultural production and resource extraction; manufacturing and industrial output, first based on crafts and small manufacturing before transitioning to mass production; effectively overcoming geographical barriers to transport goods across land and sea; excellence in the fields that facilitated trade, both within the United States and globally, including banking and finance, insurance, accounting, and law; and communicating over longer distances and at increasing volume and speed.

    America’s impressive and sustained economic success has been based on a number of factors. It possesses enormous amounts of fertile land and diverse natural resources, as well as navigable rivers, excellent access to two oceans and a gulf, with good ports. It has long emphasized early education and historically had high levels of literacy and numeracy. America’s legal system prioritizes the protection of private property, both physical and intellectual. Relatively open and large-scale immigration injected youth and creativity into the population at key moments. American politics and culture incentivize entrepreneurship and small business creation. World leading research organizations, especially American universities, have consistently generated inventions, innovation, and adaptation. This history is deeply stained, of course, by a multitude of sins, the worst being the horrific legacy of slavery and persistent racism toward black Americans. Compared to its competitors, the United States has demonstrated an ability and at times a willingness to acknowledge and work to correct these pathologies, if too slowly and far from completely.

    What role has national policy played in America’s economic well-being? Over its history, the federal government has had six primary responsibilities regarding the economy. The first is national tax and budgetary policy, including debt management, which is largely shaped by the Congress in cooperation with the executive branch. The second is monetary policy. Both were transformed in 1913, when the United States inaugurated a peacetime income tax and created the Federal Reserve banking system. The third is land policy — how would the United States distribute and regulate its vast territory? Fourth is regulatory, competition, and antitrust policy, another largely 20th century innovation that the progressives initiated and more fully emerged during President Franklin Roosevelt’s New Deal. The fifth, social welfare, insurance, and health provision, also emerged from the New Deal but expanded significantly under President Lyndon Johnson’s Great Society programs, supplemented by health care expansion under Presidents George W. Bush and Barack Obama. The sixth — and the only one that deals explicitly with international economics — is tariff and trade policy. Despite the global component, however, tariffs and trade were seen until the 20th century as the primary source of federal revenue and a way to protect nascent American manufacturing, agriculture, and industry.

    These six roles seem impressive. The U.S. national government, however, has always done less in each of these categories and in overall management of the economy than other advanced countries. On many aspects of domestic life affecting most Americans, ranging from education to criminal justice to transportation, local and state governments matter more. Even regulatory and social transformations ushered in by the New Deal and Great Society reflected far less intervention than, say, the actions taken by national governments in France, Germany, the United Kingdom, Japan, or China.

    In addition, most U.S. economic policy is overwhelmingly focused on the domestic economy, and its percentage of gross domestic product that comes from trade is lower than others. Unlike most other nations, whose monetary policy is as much concerned with the external value of its currency, the United States rarely worried about formal exchange rate policy. While the American economy is obviously influenced by the global economy, and the economy of the rest of the world has long been affected by the United States, foreign economic policy plays a less prominent role than it does in many other countries.

    The United States Is Different 

    The relatively small role of the federal government, at least compared to other states, and its focus on its domestic economy highlight a few of the ways the United States views the relationship between economics and national security that are somewhat different from other powers, both in the past and today.

    Historically, the United States has an attitude toward the international economic activity that can be puzzling to other countries. For example, the United States has throughout its history been less dependent on trade than most other powers. It possesses a massive domestic market, which it has focused on developing. Much of its trade is with its neighbors Mexico and Canada. And contrary to conventional wisdom, it has never been a free trade country. It has always employed tariffs, often quite high, both to generate government revenues (in the 19th century) and protect and nurture nascent domestic industries.

    On the other hand, while it has not been a free trade country, it has always passionately believed in the freedom to trade. For the United States, trade has always been about more than economic gain. The founders believed that commerce, between peoples and nations, was the best way to guarantee peace between states. When this freedom to trade was threatened, the United States became apoplectic: The War of 1812 and the U.S. intervention in World War I were arguably driven in large measure by outrage over interference with American freedom to trade with whomever it wanted. The United States has sometimes taken the complete opposite track when the freedom to trade is threatened, seeking to isolate itself from global commerce. Thomas Jefferson’s Embargo Acts and much of U.S. foreign economic policy during the 1930s (and to a lesser extent, the 1970s) reflected this instinct. War, on the one hand, and self-isolation, on the other, while wildly different responses, were two sides of the same coin. America does not believe anyone should curtail its freedom to engage the world through the peace-inducing qualities of mutually beneficial commerce. Arguably, these responses had less to do with geopolitics (each was potentially foolish), or even wealth, given the relatively small exposure the U.S. economy had to trade. Rather, they emanated from a broad set of principles and frames for how the United States understood the world.

    This helps explain the significance of the much derided “open door” policy of the United States. In the late 19th and early 20th century, the European powers exploited a China rocked by deep political turmoil to carve out separate economic spheres for themselves. U.S. Secretary of State John Hay tried to establish the principle that no state should have exclusive trading rights in any part of China and all states should be allowed to compete freely for its trade. While the open-door notes were specific to China, and the United States offered mere words and no force to back its declaration, the notes reflected principles held by the United States before and after this particular episode. It was less about economic gain — trade with China played a negligible role in the overall American economy — than the idea that a world where sovereign states were allowed to trade freely was one that would be more peaceful. This highlights another key part of America’s philosophy toward economics and security — its profound disapproval of formal empire, which it associated with dangerous European behavior.

    Academics have argued endlessly about America’s historical attitude toward empire. It is correctly pointed out that America’s relentless drive to establish continental hegemony in North America over native populations was perhaps the most extreme form of imperialism. The United States also acquired island territories in the Caribbean and Pacific. It fought a brutal counter-insurgency in the Philippines, while allowing itself to routinely intervene in the domestic affairs of its Latin American neighbors. If imperialism is defined in the broadest possible way — to include cultural influence and economic sway — the United States rivals any historical hegemon.

    Unlike the European empires, however, the United States sensed from its founding that the process of acquiring, subduing, and exploiting overseas colonies for economic gain was politically corrupting, both by poisoning domestic institutions and making international affairs more prone to war. The political logic was simple but profound: Formal empire exploits people unjustly and can be maintained only through coercion. Coercion requires expensive standing militaries and large, intrusive bureaucracies, which demand high taxation; highly regulated, often mercantilist economies; and powerful, often non-representative central governments. And the more militarized the world, the greater temptation to resort to force. In a world without empire and formal colonies, however, large militaries, higher taxation, and overweening central governments are less needed. Citizens can pursue gain and mutual benefit through commerce, which leads to peace among nations. There is no doubt this stylized understanding of world politics contained within it contradictions and elements of hypocrisy. To an extent rarely recognized, however, the United States associated European empire with tyranny and war, and saw free commerce as a way to avoid those evils.

    American Foreign Economic Policy After 1945

    The United States abandoned its hands-off relationship with the international economy as a result of World War II. A variety of considerations motivated this shift, including its own economic fears. Contrary to critical accounts, however, economic order building was inspired less by a desire to create an American empire, formal or informal, than to break what it saw as the links between empire, autarky, and war. A world with stable, mutually beneficial trade was more likely to be prosperous and peaceful. These goals motivated a variety of initiatives, ranging from the institutions and rules that emerged from the 1944 Bretton Woods conference to the Marshall Plan.

    It is important to remember that the history of America’s foreign economic policy and American national security policies since 1945 followed distinct paths and histories, sometimes overlapping, sometimes at odds, other times discrete and unconnected. In other words, the history of America’s role in this global economic order is not the same as the history of the Cold War competition with the Soviet Union. Furthermore, there was not, as is often thought, a single liberal world economic order that emerged in 1945 and persists today. Instead, postwar American foreign economic policy can be divided into at least four different periods.

    The first period, the Bretton Woods era, lasted from the immediate postwar years to the early 1970s. This period was not, as often thought, animated by a desire to increase globalization, open economies, and foster interdependence. Instead, the aim was to take the best elements of the free enterprise system while avoiding its worst elements. It was believed that the interwar period revealed the dangers of unregulated globalization: international debt and massive swings in investment and capital flows leading to currency volatility, which in turn created pressures for economic nationalism, trade blocs, and beggar-thy-neighbor economic policies. These in turn encouraged autarky on one hand and imperial preferences on the other, generating (at least in the minds of American statesmen) the seeds of authoritarianism, war, and conquest. The statesmen who met at Bretton Woods in 1944 sought above all else to stabilize currencies, even at the expense of free trade and capital movements, and prioritized domestic economic priorities and national reconstruction, as well as regional integration, over globalization and free trade.

    The Bretton Woods system successfully achieved its goals — a postwar depression was avoided and Western Europe and Japan recovered and grew rapidly. The system possessed the seeds of its own dissolution, however. Fixed exchange rates are difficult to maintain for long periods. Diverging rates of inflation between countries change the real value of the currency, unless there is a mechanism to readjust those values. Before World War II, the movement of gold to cover balance of payments deficits was supposed to do the trick. Since national monetary supplies were based on gold, losing the metal to cover deficits required raising interest rates and deflating the domestic economy to return it to balance of payments equilibrium. The link between gold, the balance of payments, and the domestic economy was largely broken in the postwar period. No national government, least of all that of the United States, would deflate its economy and increase unemployment to balance its international payments. The United States refused to undertake either the domestic or international policies that would have been needed to maintain the fixed exchange rate regime, which began unraveling in the 1960s before collapsing in the early 1970s.

    The second postwar period of U.S. foreign economic policy was the early 1970s through the early 1990s, which might be thought of as the most volatile, disruptive period of globalization. Efforts to reconstitute the fixed exchange rates failed and international capital flows ballooned. At the same time, increasing commodity prices, wage pressures, and loose monetary policies unleashed inflation. Large segments of the domestic economy were deregulated. Despite efforts in the 1980s to create trade, financial, and exchange rate stability, both the domestic and international economy were marked by crises — Third World debt, U.S. budget and balance of payments deficits, higher interest rates, and the collapse of the domestic savings and loan industry. While the American economy grew (erratically), the system could have come off the rails, and in many ways, the collapse of communism in the Soviet Union and Eastern Europe masked some of the deep problems within the post-Bretton Woods system.

    The third period, which began in the early 1990s and lasted through the 2008 global financial crisis, might be thought of as the period of unfettered globalization or the so-called Washington consensus, which emphasized fiscal responsibility, monetary stability, privatization, and the increased global movement of goods, capital, and ideas. The United States managed to get its own domestic house in order, driving down its budget deficits, lowering its interest rates, and benefiting from the productivity gains emerging from the nascent technology revolution in Silicon Valley. The World Trade Organization was created in 1995 and China was welcomed as a member in 2001, massively increasing global trade. The system did have crises in Mexico in 1994 and Russia and East Asia in 1998, but global growth, especially in East Asia, was impressive.

    The fourth period was the 2008 crisis and its aftermath, and we are still trying to make sense of it. On the one hand, innovative policies, both by the Obama administration and Ben Bernanke’s Federal Reserve, likely prevented a deep recession from developing into a global depression. On the other hand, the economic recovery was slow and often inequitable, and a dissatisfaction with the politics of both the crisis and recovery helped drive populist nationalism, both in the United States and abroad. Arguably, no real economic “system” emerged from the crisis, either at home or internationally, offering the Biden administration an opportunity in the wake of the COVID-19 pandemic to rewrite and rebuild the rules of both the domestic and international economy, while creating a more durable, prosperous, and equitable system.

    The Way Forward?

    If the Biden administration is to place domestic and foreign economic policy at the heart of its national security strategy, there are at least five big questions about the future of the American economy and how it relates to U.S. national security strategy that must be examined.

    First, how will the United States respond to the ongoing transformation of the domestic and international economy? Economic success going forward will be less based on traditional measures and low value-added activities, such as agriculture, resource extraction, low-end services, and even mass industrial prowess. Growth will increasingly emerge from generating and implementing technological innovations, as well as from the ability to creatively finance them. New technological breakthroughs in AI and machine learning, quantum computing, automation and robotics, 3D printing and advanced manufacturing, biomedicine, nanotechnology, etc. have the potential to revolutionize fields ranging from energy and health to manufacturing and transportation. Will the United States generate and adapt to these innovations, while also providing its population with the skills necessary to thrive in this new world? Success in the technology and financial realm have also tended to increase inequality, while also worsening geographical divisions between innovation hubs (Boston, San Francisco, New York, Austin) and other parts of the country. Will the government devise wise policies to ameliorate these frictions without losing the benefits of innovation?

    How this question is answered is largely a matter of domestic politics. Yet how it is answered will shape both America’s global competitiveness and its political and societal well-being.

    Relatedly, will the United States reject globalization and turn inward? In many communities, intense globalization is associated with de-industrialization and offshoring, despair and the opioid crisis, debt and inequality, climate change, and the rise of China. The United States has, throughout its history, gone through periods where it has turned its gaze away from the international economy. These historical episodes have rarely ended happily. Is there a way to capture the benefits of globalization while minimizing the harmful excesses?

    The third question concerns the future of America’s economic relationship to China. The argument for decoupling and reducing vulnerability to China is powerful. First, COVID-19 demonstrated the dangers of vulnerable supply chains. Second, it does not make sense to continue to enrich a current and future rival. Third, increasing automation and robotics means that labor cost differentials are a less compelling reason to offshore production. For those who are skeptical of the pacifying effects of interdependence and believe security concerns should always trump economic ones, pulling away from China’s economy is the obvious choice.

    The problem is that left to its own devices, the American and Chinese economies won’t naturally decouple. General Motors sells more cars, and Apple has sold more iPhones, in China than in the United States. Supply chains remain deeply integrated, including on the high-end technology front. Dissolving those relationships will be costly. Trade today is less between countries than within firms, whose operations are global rather than national. Shared technology platforms increase productivity, which would be lost under decoupling.

    Trade flows, however, do not begin to capture the deep integration between the two economies. The financial and monetary spheres are far more interconnected. Chinese companies are raising record amounts on Wall Street, while U.S. banks and financial firms increase their investment and business in China. Despite political strains over the past decade, direct investment and financing in both directions shows little signs of decreasing. Reversing economic interdependence — if that policy is chosen for national security purposes — will both be costly and require political will. It would also fully signal that the United States sees China not as a competitor or even a rival, but as a full-blown adversary.

    What are the sources of innovation and adaptation, and what role will the national government play in facilitating creating, scaling up, and implementing new technologies? This is the fourth big question faced by the Biden administration, and the issue here will be shaped by its view of U.S. competition and antitrust policy. On the one hand, the recent computing and telecommunications revolution has revealed the power of companies that dominate networks and platforms. The United States has done very well in this new world, and there are important arguments that the government should applaud and support the success of American tech giants dominating the global economy. On the other hand, some experts question whether it is healthy from a competition, innovation, and fairness perspective to allow companies like Amazon, Apple, Google, and Microsoft to achieve such dominating market power. They harken back to the spirit of President Theodore Roosevelt and his controversial but popular program of trust-busting in the early 20th century. There are critical national security considerations to both views.

    Relatedly, there is a long-debated question of the role the government should play in seeding, supporting, subsidizing, and even directing the private sector. The United States has long steered clear of national economic planning. Yet the Chinese government’s massive, directed investments and championing of its companies, both for economic and national security reasons, has caused many Americans to rethink their priors on the relationship between the state and the private sector. This is reflected in the impressive, bipartisan support for the Endless Frontier Act to support improved technological competitiveness vis-à-vis China.

    The final question involves America’s role as the banker to the world. Will the United States continue in this role, and what will the consequences be? This question has two parts, the first involving international monetary policy, the second surrounding capital formation.

    One of the most important global economic developments of the past 15 years has been the emergence of the Federal Reserve Bank as the lender of last resort, not just to the United States, but to the world. The Federal Reserve banking system demonstrated masterful adaptability and far-sighted innovation during both the 2008 financial crisis and the economic fallout from last year’s COVID-19 crisis that, in both cases, arguably prevented a global depression and increased its mandate well beyond securing the U.S. financial system. In the process, it quietly but significantly increased America’s already potent global monetary and financial power. Despite previous predictions to the contrary, it is and will remain for some time a dollar-dominated world. Will this increased monetary power marry up with America’s recent proclivity to deploy economic sanctions, and if so, will that add or diminish American economic influence over the long term?

    Part of the answer will be shaped by the uncertain outcome of current economic policies. The United States is currently undergoing a consequential experiment, with relative loose fiscal and monetary policy leading to a rethinking of how much debt and liquidity the economy can contain. Will this produce destabilizing inflation and a return to 1970s stagflation? Or will this liquidity be efficiently absorbed into higher productivity, a reduction in inequality, and overall growth? Interest rates, both nationally and around the world, remain near historical lows, despite the surge in liquidity.

    The second aspect to America’s global financial power comes in its world leading innovation, sophistication, and depth of its financial sector. In recent decades, New York City competed with Hong Kong and London as the best place to raise capital and list companies. As recently as a decade ago, New York’s competitors showed signs of taking the lead. Great Britain’s decision to leave the European Union and China’s decision to crack down on dissent in Hong Kong has moved the advantages back to the United States. In addition to the traditional methods of Wall Street finance and exchange listings, America’s innovative venture capital financing capabilities in Silicon Valley, Boston, Austin, and elsewhere provide important and impressive domestic and global advantages. Can they be maintained and expanded upon?

    Conclusion 

    Will the Biden administration’s efforts to link economic and national security succeed? While a commendable goal, accomplishing it may not be as easy or simple as one might think. To do so, U.S. officials would be wise to recognize the complex, often contradictory factors shaping economic and security goals, calculating how best to resolve the tension while advancing both. Foreign economic policy is about a lot more than trade policy, for example, and the most effective long-term policy toward China likely eludes simple binaries. They should also keep in mind America’s unique history and perspective on the purpose of economic statecraft, which is often at odds with other countries. Finally, the administration should recognize and generate policies to deal with the profound economic changes wrought by the larger technological and financial transformation of both the national and global economies. The United States is at an inflection point, both in how its economy operates and in the global security landscape it faces. How it handles the balance between the two — generating wealth while also creating security — will have consequences for years to come.

    Francis J. Gavinis the Giovanni Agnelli Distinguished Professor and the inaugural director of the Henry A. Kissinger Center for Global Affairs at Johns Hopkins School of Advanced International Studies. He is also the Chairman of the Board of Editors of the Texas National Security Review. Gavin has written several books, including Gold, Dollars, and Power: The Politics of International Monetary Relations, 1958-1971.

    Image: U.S. Air Force (Photo by Staff Sgt. Christopher S. Muncy)

    Adblock test (Why?)


    Economics and US National Security - War on the Rocks
    Read More

    Atlanta Fed chief to head chamber in 2022, sees diversity as economic fuel - The Atlanta Journal Constitution

    AJC - Logo - Main logo_ddn_tag_Site JN with T...